Assessing the Contribution of Carbon Emissions Trading in China to Carbon Intensity Reduction

来源 :Energy Science and Technology | 被引量 : 0次 | 上传用户:Neldaking
下载到本地 , 更方便阅读
声明 : 本文档内容版权归属内容提供方 , 如果您对本文有版权争议 , 可与客服联系进行内容授权或下架
论文部分内容阅读
  [a]Department of Social Engineering, Tokyo Institute of Technology, 2-12-1 Ookayama, Meguro-ku, Tokyo 152-8550, Japan.
  [b]Department of Social Engineering, Tokyo Institute of Technology, 2-12-1 Ookayama, Meguro-ku, Tokyo 152-8550, Japan.
  *Corresponding author.
  Supported by the Environment Research and Technology Development Fund (A-1103) of the Ministry of the Environment, Government of Japan.
  Received 28 May 2012; accepted 3 August 2012
  Abstract
  This paper assesses the impacts of emissions trading between Jiangxi Province and the Rest of China on the carbon prices, total cost of carbon reduction and GDP loss using a two-region provincial Computable General Equilibrium model developed for China. The results reveal that without emissions trading, the carbon prices in 2020 would be 46.8 US$ in Jiangxi Province and 23.2 US$ in the rest of China, leading to GDP loss of 1.07% and 0.79% respectively. However, if emissions trading is allowed between provinces, Jiangxi Province needs to import CO2 emissions allowance from the rest of China. In 2013, the trading amount is 14.30 million ton or 7.84% of total CO2 emissions of Jiangxi Province. In 2020, the trading amount triples as compared to 2013, to a level of 44.85 million ton, accounting for 19.37% of Jiangxi’s total emissions. The results also reveal that the total costs of Jiangxi Province and the whole China would fall due to emissions trading, which is consistent with the theoretical implications. It is found that in the case of emissions trading, the GDP loss in 2020 would be lower for Jiangxi Province, at 0.36% instead of 1.07%.
  Key words: Domestic carbon emissions trading; 2-regional CGE model; China
  Dai, H., & Masui, T. (2012). Assessing the Contribution of Carbon Emissions Trading in China to Carbon Intensity Reduction. Energy Science and Technology, 4(1), -0. Available from: URL: http://www.cscanada.net/index.php/est/article/view/10.3968/j.est.1923847920120401.456
  DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.3968/j.est.1923847920120401.456
  INTRODUCTION
  Emissions trading as originally described by Dales[1] is seen as a market-based instrument to efficiently reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Participants, which could be an entire industry, country, or a set of countries, are allocated a certain quantity of emission allowances within a specified period. If participants want to emit more/fewer emissions than covered by their allowances, they can either buy or sell allowances. As market theory proposes, the participants will adjust their buying and selling behaviour according to their marginal abatement costs. If marginal abatement costs are higher than the price of allowances, participants will buy additional allowances; if they are lower, it is beneficial to sell allowances or to buy fewer[2, 3].   One advantage of emissions trading is that reductions are achieved where one ton of carbon dioxide can be avoided most cost-effectively. Therefore, emissions trading minimizes the total cost to the economy of all avoidance measures. Another potential advantage is that the resulting carbon price would improve long-term predictability, a crucial factor for businesses to make efficient investment decisions. In the long run, emissions trading will lead to the deployment of more efficient technologies and to an increased availability of renewable energy[4]. However, these advantages are based on the assumption of a perfect market, complete information and rational behavior by all market players. This assumption does not hold in practice and that leads to serious market failures[3].
  So far, there are several emissions trading schemes. On a global level, emissions trading between governments has been established as one of three flexible mechanisms in the framework of the Kyoto Protocol. On the national level, many industrialized countries have either introduced or are considering company-based emissions trading systems, such as the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI) in the north-east of the US, in California or the various proposals for a US cap-and-trade scheme in the US Senate or in Australia 11[4]. On the supranational level, the European Union established today’s largest company-based greenhouse gas emissions trading scheme which is operating since 2005. It encompasses about 11,500 installations from all its Member States, responsible for around a third of the EU’s greenhouse gas emissions, and roughly 45% of the EU’s CO2 emissions[5].
  In the past decades, China has transformed from an agriculture-based to an industry-based country. At the same time, its growth has been driven by a large, growing trade surplus and rising investment in energy-intensive sectors rather than domestic consumption, which partially led to China’s growing demand for energy and rocketing CO2 emissions in the early 2000s[6]. After overtaking United States as the largest carbon dioxide (CO2) emission country in 2007, China again surpassed United States and became the world’s top energy consumer in 2010[7]. For this reason China is faced with mounting pressures to take on emissions commitments and energy conservation. As a reaction to the pressure and in order to resolve the conflicts between energy supply and demand, as well as to address the related environmental problems, the Chinese government has made significant efforts to formulate energy-saving and climate policies. In 2009, China committed to lower its CO2 emissions per unit of gross domestic product (GDP) by 40-45% by 2020 compared to the 2005 level, and increase the share of non-fossil fuels in primary energy consumption to around 15% by 2020[8]. In order to fulfill the commitment, China has made stepwise five-year targets to cut the energy intensity by 20% and 16% in its Eleventh (2006-2010) and Twelfth (2011-2015) Five-Year Plans for National Economic and Social Development[9,10], respectively. By 2010, China almost achieved the first target with the actual energy intensity and carbon intensity in terms of GDP decreasing by 19.1% and 17%, respectively. Furthermore, China has launched substantive initiatives at both national and provincial levels to promote low carbon development. The National Development and Reform Commission of China (NDRC) has decided to run the first pilots for low carbon development in five provinces and eight cities. The selected provinces and cities are required to carry out actions such as making low-carbon development plan, developing policy to support low-carbon development, accelerating the establishment of industries characterized by low carbon emissions, and proactively advocating low-carbon green lifestyle[11]. More recently, China has decided to establish carbon emissions trading market in China[10].   So far, very few studies deal with China’s domestic emissions trading and its impacts on the economy and energy consumption. In this context, this study aims to assess the carbon emissions trading at provincial level using a two-region CGE model developed for China. This model and analysis could be applied to any province given the necessary dataset.
  Jiangxi Province is selected as an example. Jiangxi is an inland province located in southeast of China. Its population (39.66 million) and area are 3.35% and 1.74% of whole China, respectively. Jiangxi is a rather poor province when compared to its neighboring provinces. In 2009, its GDP was 765 billion yuan (112.1 billion USD, per capita 2515 USD), accounting for 2.10% of total GDP of China[12].
  The emissions target is set in such a way that the carbon intensity of GDP will be reduced by 45% in 2020 compared to 2005. We would like to assess the carbon prices, economic impacts of emissions reduction in the cases of with and without emissions trading, as well as the potential amount of emissions trading and implications for energy consumption.
  The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 1 introduces the CGE model. Section 2 shows the results with respect to energy intensity and carbon intensity, energy consumption and CO2 emissions, carbon prices and emissions trading, and GDP change due to carbon constraints and emissions trading. The paper concludes with some final remarks at the end of this paper.
  1. METHODOLOGY
  Scenario analysis is conducted using a two-region recursive dynamic CGE model extended from the static and dynamic version for China[13, 14]. There are two regions in this model, Jiangxi Province and the Rest of China, which interact with each other through domestic trade. The model includes a production module, final demand modules by government and household, a domestic transaction module and an international transaction module. Various key technologies are considered in the energy intensive sectors, such as non-fossil electricity generation, alternative fuel production (bio-liquid and bio-gas), carbon capture and storage (CCS). The model is solved by GAMS/MPSGE[15].
  1.1 Production Sector
  There are 41 sectors in this model, seven of which are energy sectors (Table 1). Sectors are classified into basic, land-requiring, resource-requiring, and energy transformation sectors. Activity output of each sector follows a nested constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function. Inputs are categorized into material commodities, energy commodities, traditional biomass, land, labor, capital and resource. The technologies include power generation technologies and CCS technologies as well as biomass to liquid and biomass to gas technologies. Activity output is determined by the aggregation of fixed coefficients of non-energy and energy intermediate commodities, traditional biomass, and primary factors. The composite of non-energy inputs is in Leontief form. Energy and value added bundle is nested by valued added and energy inputs. Value added bundle is a CES function of primary factors. The composite of energy inputs is a CES aggregation of electricity and fossil fuels. Fossil fuels are further disaggregated into five types. Data for elasticity of substitution in energy bundle were adopted from Li[16] and Wu[17].   Table 1
  Sector/Commodity Definition in the Model
  1.2 Household and Government Sectors
  Household and government are final consumers. The representative household receives income from the rental of primary factors and lump-sum transfer from the government. The income is used for either investment or consumption. Household maximizes its utility by choosing the levels of consumption of commodities, subject to the constraints of its income and commodity prices.
  The government collects taxes, including carbon tax, and the revenue from carbon tax is recycled to the representative agent as a lump-sum transfer. Based on a Cobb-Douglas demand function[18], the government also spends its revenue on public services which are provided to the whole society and on goods and services which are provided to the households free of charge or at low prices[19].
  1.3 Domestic and International Transaction
  The produced goods and commodities are distributed to international and domestic markets first. Like most other country CGE models, this model assumes a small open economy, meaning that the economy is small enough for its policies not to alter world prices or incomes. Future international prices are assumed to be at a constant level for non-energy commodities and increase by 3% yearly for energy commodities from 2005 onwards. Produced goods are distributed to domestic and international markets with an elasticity of transformation of 2. Within the domestic markets, the products are sold either in the local market or rest of China with the elasticity of transformation being 3. The Armington assumption is used to distinguish identical local goods, goods from other provinces, and imported goods. The elasticity of substitution between imported and domestic goods is adopted from Li[16] (Appendix A1), while that between local market and the other provinces is twice as high as import/domestic value.
  1.4 Base Year Data
  The dataset used in this model includes an input-output table[19, 20], energy balance table[21], GHG emission factors, and data on characteristics of electricity generation technologies. All the datasets are converted to the base year of 2005. Detailed description of these datasets could be found in Dai et al.[13].
  1.5 Dynamic Process and Scenario
  As a recursive dynamic CGE model in which the agents’ behavior is based on adaptive expectations rather than forward-looking expectations, the model is solved one period at a time[22], and the selected parameters, including capital stock, labor force, land, energy efficiency, total factor productivity, labor productivity, land productivity and the extraction cost of fossil fuels, are updated based on the modeling of inter-temporal behavior and results from previous periods.   This study analyzes three scenarios, including the Reference Scenario (RS), NoTRADE scenario and TRADE scenario (Table 2).
  All scenarios share some common assumptions in population, investment, AEEI, and total factor productivity (TFP), and other parameters. AEEI is assumed separately for liquid, solid and gas fuels. AEEI of gas fuel is -1%, reflecting the fact that fuel switch to natural gas will take place naturally in future. Non-fossil fuel use, including nuclear power, hydro power, solar power, wind power and biomass, follows the assumption in the report released by Energy Research Institute[23]. We also assume the economy will decouple from the energy intensive products such as cement, iron and steel, chemistry products and paper, reflecting the dematerialization trend in the future[24-26].
  The scenarios differ from each other in the assumption on emissions trading and carbon emissions cap. In RS, no carbon emissions constraint is imposed on China. In the other two scenarios, carbon intensity of GDP will reduce by 45% in 2020 compared to 2005 in both Jiangxi Province and the rest of China. However, the NoTRADE scenario doesn’t allow emissions trading, while in the scenario TRADE free emissions trading between the two regions is allowed.
  Table 2
  Key Assumptions in Scenarios
  Data source[23, 27]
  2. RESULT
  In this part we show the results of energy and CO2 emissions, energy and carbon intensity, carbon prices and emissions trading, and GDP change due to carbon constraints and emissions trading.
  2.1 Energy and Carbon Intensity
  In 2005, carbon and energy intensities of Jiangxi Province are lower than the rest of China (Figure 1), reflecting the fact that Jiangxi Province is relatively underdeveloped where the agriculture and light industry dominate its economy.
  In the reference scenario, the intensities in both regions fall steadily from 2005 to 2020 due to energy price increase and technology improvements such as energy efficiency improvement and factor productivity improvement. However, even though the energy intensities of both regions reduce at same speed, by about 29% in 2020 compared with 2005, the speed of carbon intensity improvement is different; the carbon intensity of the Rest of China falls by 29% while that of Jiangxi Province falls by only 21%. The reason is that relatively more renewable energy is used in the Rest of China throughout 2020, but the energy consumption increase of Jiangxi Province derives mainly from carbon intensive coal and oil.   In the carbon constraint scenarios, without emission trading, carbon intensities of Jiangxi Province and the Rest of China reduce by 44.3% and 44.6%, respectively. China’s Copenhagen climate commitment in 2009 is achieved. However, with emissions trading, the actual carbon intensity of Jiangxi Province reduces only by 34.0%, which is lower than the previous reduction of 44.3%. On the other hand, the carbon intensity of the Rest of China reduces by 44.8%, which is slightly higher than without emission trading scenario.
  Figure 1
  Carbon (Upper Two) and Energy (Lower Two) Intensity Trajectory
  2.2 CO2 Emissions and Energy Consumption
  In contrast to intensity reduction, CO2 emissions and energy consumption increase in all scenarios and regions due to the main driving force of tremendous per capita GDP increase (Figure 2). If China achieves the Copenhagen carbon intensity reduction target, the total emissions and energy consumption would be lower than in the reference scenario.
  With emissions trading, the actual emissions of Jiangxi Province are higher than in without emissions trading’s case, which leads to higher actual carbon and energy intensities as mentioned in the previous section. This implies that Jiangxi Province needs to import carbon emissions allowance from the Rest of China. The reason will be explained in the next section by shedding light on carbon price difference between the two regions.
  Figure 2
  Total CO2 Emissions (Upper Two) and Primary Energy Supply (Lower Two)
  2.3 Carbon Price and Carbon Emissions Trading
  The previous results imply that Jiangxi Province needs to import carbon emissions allowance from the Rest of China. In fact, as showed in Figure 3, the emissions trading starts from 2013, immediately after carbon constraints are imposed. The trading amount is 14.3 million ton of CO2 in 2013 and increases drastically to 44.9 million ton in 2020, accounting for 7.8% and 19.4% of total emissions of Jiangxi Province in those years, respectively.
  The emissions trading takes place because of the carbon price difference between the two regions. As shown in Figure 3, without emissions trading, the carbon price of Jiangxi Province is always around two times as high as the Rest of China during 2013 to 2020, which results in the necessity of import of carbon allowance for Jiangxi Province. When emissions could be traded freely, the carbon prices of both regions become equal, and the carbon price of Jiangxi Province falls by around 50% while that of the Rest of China increase slightly by 1-2%. Carbon reductions are achieved where one ton of carbon dioxide can be avoided most cost-effectively, which is consistent with the economic theory.   Figure 3
  Carbon Prices and Emissions Trade
  2.4 Economic Impacts
  After analyzing the influences of emissions trading on carbon prices and emission reduction costs, we now present the results of economic impacts. As illustrated in Figure 4, without emissions trading the GDP loss of Jiangxi Province in 2020 is 1.07%, whereas with emissions trading the GDP loss becomes much less at 0.36% as a result of decrease in carbon reduction cost. The economic impacts of emissions trading on the Rest of China are little since the change in carbon price is insignificant.
  Figure 4
  GDP in the Reference Scenario (Pillar) and GDP Change (Line) in the Other Scenarios Compared to the Reference Scenario
  DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION
  In this paper we have analyzed the emissions trading at provincial level in China using a two-region recursive dynamic CGE model. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first attempt to assess China’s domestic emissions trading and its impacts on the carbon price, carbon reduction cost, and the economy. In principle, this two-region model could be applied to any other province in China and other countries given the necessary dataset.
  It is clear from the results that since Jiangxi province has an underdeveloped economy with relatively little heavy industry, its energy intensity is 25% lower than in the Rest of China in 2005. However, despite the lower energy intensity the carbon intensity is almost the same as in the rest of China. This is because the share of carbon intensive coal and oil being 95% in 2005, Jiangxi Province’s energy composition is more carbon intensive that the Rest of China (fossil energy share being 93% in the latter). Even without carbon constraints, the carbon intensity and energy intensity would reduce in both regions due to energy price increase and technology improvement, but the naturally occurring reductions are not sufficient to achieve China’s Copenhagen Commitment of 45% carbon intensity reduction. Additional mitigation policy such as carbon tax must be introduced.
  If carbon constraints are imposed on the economy of Jiangxi Province and the Rest of China without emissions trading, the carbon prices in 2020 would be 46.8 US$ and 23.2 US$ in the two regions, respectively. The corresponding reduction costs in the two regions are 1.08 and 25.8 billion US$, leading to GDP loss of 1.07% for Jiangxi Province and 0.79% for the rest of China.
  However, the picture would be different if the emissions trading scheme is introduced. Since the carbon prices in the Rest of China are merely half of Jiangxi Province in the whole period of 2013 to 2020, it is cost effective to reduce CO2 emissions in the Rest of China. Therefore, it is beneficial for Jiangxi Province to import CO2 emissions allowance from the Rest of China. In 2013, the trading amount is 14.30 million ton CO2 or 7.84% of total CO2 emissions of Jiangxi Province. With time Jiangxi Province depends more and more on emissions import from the Rest of China. In 2020, for example, the trading amount triples as compared to 2013, to 44.85 million ton, accounting for 19.37% of Jiangxi’s total emissions. The results also reveal that the GDP loss would be lower for Jiangxi Province in the case of emissions trading, at 0.36% instead of 1.07%.   REFERENCES
  [1] Dales, J. H. (1968). Pollution, Property & Prices: An Essay in Policy-Making and Economic. Edward Elgar Pub.
  [2] Braun, M. (2009). The Evolution of Emissions Trading in the European Union-The Role of Policy Networks, Knowledge and Policy Entrepreneurs. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34(3-4), 469-487.
  [3] Jaehn, F., & Letmathe, P. (2009) The Emissions Trading Paradox. European Journal of Operational Research, 202(1), 248-254.
  [4] Egenhofer, C. (2007). The Making of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme: Status, Prospects and Implications for Business. European Management Journal, 25(6), 453-463.
  [5] Vis, P. (2006). Basic Design Options for Emissions Trading, in the EU Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading Scheme (pp. 39-62). Leuven: Claeys & Casteels.
  [6] Lardy, N. R. (2007). China: Rebalancing Economic Growth, in the China Balance Sheet in 2007 and Beyond. In C. F. Bergsten, et al. (Eds.). Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.
  [7] The China Times. (2011, August). China’s Energy Consumption Surpassed the U.S. in 2010. Retrieved from http://www.thechinatimes.com/online/2011/06/137.html
  [8] National Development and Reform Commission of China (NDRC). (2010, September). Letter Including Autonomous Domestic Mitigation Actions. Retrieved from http://unfccc.int/files/meetings/application/pdf/chinacphaccord_app2.pdf
  [9] National People’s Congress. (2006). The Eleventh Five-Year Plan for National Economic and Social Development (in Chinese). Beijing: People’s Education Press.
  [10] National People’s Congress. (2010). The Twelfth Five-Year Plan for National Economic and Social Development (in Chinese). Beijing: People’s Education Press.
  [11] National Development and Reform Commission of China (NDRC). (2010). National Development and Reform Commission on Pilot Work in Low-Carbon Provinces and Cities (in Chinese). NDRC Climate Doc, No.15872010b.
  [12] National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS). (2010). China Statistical Year Book 2010. Beijing: China Statistics Press.
  [13] Dai, H., et al. (2011). Assessment of China’s Climate Commitment and Non-Fossil Energy Plan Towards 2020 Using Hybrid AIM/CGE Model. Energy Policy, 39(5), 2875-2887.
  [14] Dai, H., et al. (in press). The Impacts of China’s Household Consumption Expenditure Patterns on Energy Demand and Carbon Policy up to 2050.
  [15] Rutherford, T. F. (1999). Applied General Equilibrium Modeling with MPSGE as a GAMS Subsystem: An Overview of the Modeling Framework and Syntax. Computational Economics, 14(1-2), 1-46.   [16] Li, N. (2010). A Multi-Regional CGE Model for Policy Simulation on Regional Development (in Chinese). CAS Research Center on Fictitious Economy & Data Sciences. Beijing: Graduate University of Chinese Academy of Sciences.
  [17] Wu, Y., & Xuan, X. (2002). The Theory of Environmental Tax and Its Application in China. Beijing: Economic Science Press.
  [18] Hertel, T. W., & Tsigas, M. E. (2004). Structure of GTAP, in Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications (pp. 48). New York: Cambridge University Press.
  [19] National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS). (2002). Input-output Tables of China 2002 (in Chinese). Beijing: China Statistics Press.
  [20] Peng, Z. (2009). Input-Output Tables of China (2007). Beijing: China Statistics Press.
  [21] National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS). (2006). China Energy Statistical Year Book 2006 (in Chinese). Beijing: China Statistics Press.
  [22] Thurlow, J. (2008). A Recursive Dynamic CGE Model and Microsimulation Poverty Module for South Africa. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.
  [23] Jiang, K., & Hu, X. (2009). 2050 China Energy and CO2 Emissions Scenario, in China’s Low Carbon Development Pathways by 2050. Beijing: Science Press.
  [24] Kander, A. (2005). Baumol’s Disease and Dematerialization of the Economy. Ecological Economics, 55(1), 119-130.
  [25] Bernardini, O., & Galli, R. (1993). Dematerialization: Long-Term Trends in the Intensity of Use of Materials and Energy. Futures, 25(4), 431-448.
  [26] Ayres, R. U., & Van Den Bergh, J. C. J. M. (2005). A Theory of Economic Growth with Material/Energy Resources and Dematerialization: Interaction of Three Growth Mechanisms. Ecological Economics, 55(1), 96-118.
  [27] UN. (2008). World Population Prospects: The 2008 Revision Population Database. New York: United Nations.
  APPENDIX
  Table A1
  Elasticity of Substitution Between Domestic and Imported Commodities[16]
其他文献
摘要:应用型高校的旅游管理专业是为了培养导游人员和导游管理的储备人员,其教学方式和课程内容需要和时代发展相适应。“旅游政策法规”是其专业基础课程,现在的教学过程中仍然存在着一些问题,文中对其进行了分析,并提出了几点改进和创新措施,希望能够给教学工作带来帮助。  关键词:应用型高校;教学改革;旅游政策法规  中图分类号:F592.3 文献标识码:A 文章编号:1672-7517(2018)07-00
期刊
过去在学习哲学时,常说的一句话是,具体地分析具体的问题,是马克思主义活的灵魂。回顾大跃进年代。我们要否定的是那时的浮夸风、蛮干风、共产风和某些干部工作中的瞎指挥、命令主义和强迫作风等,而不是否定那时所做的一切事情。即拿兴修水利来说,早些年有资料证明,大跃进时期所修建的包括林县红旗渠、丹江口水利枢纽、密云水库、新安江水库及发电站在内的水利设施,大部分还在发挥着防洪、储水、航运、灌溉、发电和水产养殖的
期刊
你们是运行一线的先锋  你们是热电厂忠诚坚贞的守护神  披星戴月 不辞辛劳  精心监盘 精心操控  一噸吨汽 一度度电  是你们用热血谱写热电厂的辉煌人生  因为有你们无私的付出  才保证了热电厂可持续发展的永恒  你们是检修一线的精英  你们是热电厂安全运行的保护神  随叫随到 无怨无悔  精益生产 精益检修  长效出力 高效运行  是你们用赤诚书写热电厂安全的保证  因为有你们真心的牺牲  才
期刊
摘要:在近几年广受欢迎的文化旅游地产项目中,新型社区邻里关系培育受到越来越多的重视。本文以秦皇岛阿那亚项目为考察对象,通过实地考察、问卷调查、访谈、和案例分析,试图对文化旅游地产模式下新型社区邻里关系培育机制进行初步研究。  关键词:社区邻里关系;阿那亚;文化旅游地产  中图分类号:F592.3 文献标识码:A 文章编号:1672-7517(2018)07-0022-02  1 引言  文化旅游地
期刊
摘要:我国的经济发展进入新常态,对于一个企业来讲要想长远的发展,在行业中占据一席之地,提升企业的核心竞争力是极其必要的。通过分析和探讨“一带一路”的概念内涵,分析企业的发展现状,并着重研究“一带一路”背景下增强外贸企业核心竞争力的有效策略,以期能够促进我国企业核心竞争力的提升贡献一分力量。  关键词:一带一路;企业核心竞争力;科技创新;人才基础  中图分类号:F592.3 文献标识码:A 文章编号
期刊
摘要:该文主要描述了县级行政区域界线详图集的编制方案,包括已有资料的分析整理、栅格图件纠正、底图矢量化、界线更新、地图编绘及印刷装帧等内容。并描述了编制过程中技术要求、特殊问题的处理和解决以及经验总结。《详图集》按册编制,它正确地反映了勘定的县级行政区域界线位置和走向,是县级行政区域界线管理的基础,发挥突击的应用服务作用,对依法行政,解决边界争议,维护社会稳定起到重要作用。  关键词:县级行政区域
期刊
[a]College of Chemical Engineering, China University of Petroleum, Qingdao, 266555, China.  *Corresponding author.  Supported by “PetroChina Innovation Foundation (Grant No. 2011D-5006-0405) and “The
期刊
摘要:本文主要结合湖北省三国文化的历史价值和意义,通过分析本省三国文化走出去的现状,积极看待旅游英语与三国文化传承的联系,以及相关从业人员在景点翻译或讲解过程中应避免不地道表达及注意事项,推动入境旅游业大繁荣大发展,进一步提高三国文化对外知名度,塑造三国文化旅游品牌。  关键词:三国文化;旅游英语;文化传承;翻译策略  中图分类号:F59 文献标识码:A 文章编号:1672-7517(2018)0
期刊
[a]Petroleum Company of Trinidad and Tobago (Petrotrin), Trinidad and Tobago.  [b]Petroleum Engineering, Texas A&M University, College Station, Texas.  *Corresponding author.  Received 12 June 2012; a
期刊
[a]Energy Research Institute, Russian Academy of Science, Moscow, Russian Federation.  *Corresponding author.  Received 12 May 2012; accepted 14 July 2012  Abstract  Falling unconventional oil product
期刊