Why China Won’t Suffer a“Debt Crisis”

来源 :CHINA TODAY | 被引量 : 0次 | 上传用户:littleshrimp1
下载到本地 , 更方便阅读
声明 : 本文档内容版权归属内容提供方 , 如果您对本文有版权争议 , 可与客服联系进行内容授权或下架
论文部分内容阅读
  INACCURATE articles sometimes appear in the Western media claiming China faces a “severe debt crisis.” Factually these are easily refuted. Changyong Rhee, the IMF’s Asia and Pacific Department director, recently pointed out that China’s national and local government debt is only 53 percent of GDP, while the U.S. government’s debt is roughly equivalent to GDP, and Japan’s government debt is 240 percent of GDP. Foreign debt is nine percent of China’s GDP – insignificant bearing in mind that it owns the world’s largest foreign exchange reserves.
  Factually, it is therefore unsurprising that China’s predicted “Lehman” or “Minsky” moment, a financial collapse, invariably fails to occur. But there is another, even more fundamental, reason why China’s economy does not suffer severe financial crises of the type that struck the Western economies in 2008 or wracked the Eurozone. As this illustrates how China’s economic structure is superior to the West’s it is worth analyzing.
  Starting with fundamentals, the way the argument is constructed wherein China faces a “serious debt crisis” violates the most elementary accounting rule – namely that of double entry book keeping, which was invented in Italy“merely” eight centuries ago! It denotes that for every debit entry there has to be a credit one, and vice versa. Discussion of only one side of a balance sheet without the other is financial nonsense. Claims, such as in the Financial Times, that the big story of 2014 is “the black cloud of debt hanging over China” are financially meaningless given they do not discuss assets as set against debt.
  To illustrate this elementary accounting principle take a simple example. A company borrows US $100 million at 5 percent interest, uses it to build houses, and sells them at 15 percent profit. To declare “there is a crisis –the company has a US $100 million debt” is evidently nonsense. The company has debts of US $100 million but assets of US $115 million. It can repay US $105 million and make US $10 million profit – there is hence no “debt crisis” whatever. That its assets are greater than its debt illustrates why it is financially illiterate to discuss only debt without assets. A “balance sheet” is so called because it has two sides, not one.
  Apply this to China and the West’s financial systems. Evidently no financial problem exists in either if a borrower makes a profit on a loan – they repay it. A problem only exists if the borrower does not make sufficient money to repay the debt.   If the borrower is a small or medium one, again there is no difference between Western and Chinese financial systems. In both cases the borrower partially or fully defaults and, if necessary, goes bankrupt.
  Specific criticisms can be made, which this author would tend to agree with, that in the West’s system companies are sometimes too easily allowed to resort to bankruptcy to escape debts. China, meanwhile, has propped up some companies that would have been better allowed to go bankrupt. But these are details that do not affect the essence of the matter. China is now taking a more robust line in forcing into default small and medium borrowers that cannot repay loans. Shanghai Chaori Solar Energy Science and Technology recently defaulted without bailout.
  But, by definition, individual bankruptcies of small and medium companies do not affect the financial system’s viability – they are a normal part of market functioning. The key difference between Chinese and Western financial systems comes from debts by large institutions– “system making” ones to use technical economic terms. Here Western and Chinese systems differ – and China’s is superior.
  First take Western government debt. As Western governments ideologically oppose state investment, Western state borrowing is overwhelmingly used not to finance investment but consumption, via social security payments, unemployment pay and etc. For example, in the U.S. at the depth of the post 2008 Great Recession, annual government borrowing was 13.6 percent of GDP but state investment was only 4.5 percent – borrowing overwhelmingly financed consumption. As Western government debt primarily finances consumption it therefore creates no lasting asset. That is why in the West it is not wholly misleading to look at state borrowing purely from the debt point of view – even if it is wrong conceptually.
  China’s is different. The bulk of borrowing, particu-larly by local governments, is for investment, primarily in infrastructure. Borrowing therefore creates lasting assets– roads, subways and housing. Assets in turn create revenue streams directly, indirectly, or both. Direct revenues are fares, rents, and tolls. Indirect revenues are generated because infrastructure investment promotes economic growth, yields taxes, and has well-known effects in raising land values – land sales being one of Chinese local governments’ biggest sources of income.
  As China’s government debt is used for investment, not consumption, analysis that does not financially offset debt with assets created by them is not merely formally wrong but constitutes a serious actual mistake. Similarly, company borrowing is primarily used for investment, i.e. asset creation.   This leads to a final difference between China and the West. In both Western and Chinese financial systems, if the value of an asset created by borrowing equals at least the value of the debt, there is evidently no problem. The difference between the two comes with bad investments– where the value of the asset created does not equal the borrowing.
  A major financial crisis occurs when there are largescale bad investments by “system making” institutions, those that are “too big to fail.” This need not be a single bad investment but can be large numbers of small bad investments, as with the U.S. sub-prime mortgage crisis. In these cases, in both the West and China, only the state has the resources to solve the problem. But the way the state intervenes is entirely different in China and in the West.
  In the West the financial system is fragmented – individual institutions are financially separate. As there is no unified financial system, the necessary transfer of resources from the state, to prevent collapse of “system making” institutions, is therefore external and chaotic. For example, following Lehman’s collapse, essentially every private Western bank had to be salvaged by government subsidies and direct nationalization. The same occurred with GM and Chrysler. In Greece the EU and IMF ordered partial bond defaults and bailout packages. The transfer of resources from the state, and in some cases private bond holders, was via the chaotic “crisis” way –the “Lehman moment.”
  Basic laws of economics cannot be avoided, so if in China a substantial number of bad loans occur, as with banks in the 1990s, the state also has to transfer resources. But in China the core of the financial system is not fragmented, but a single integrated whole comprising central government, local governments, state banks, and large state-owned companies. Resources are therefore not transferred by chaotic crisis as in the West, but within this integrated financial system. China’s financial system could be conceptualized by the analogy of a single person transferring money from one bank account to another – for example from the central government to bail out local governments. Or, to put it more popularly, it is as though money is transferred from one pocket to another.
  A transfer of resources from the state therefore takes place in China, as in the West, but in an orderly and not a chaotic fashion. That is why China never has a “Lehman moment” or a “Minsky moment,” a large-scale financial crisis – the superiority of China’s financial system to the West precludes it happening.   To avoid misunderstandings, this does not mean that large-scale bad investments made in China do not create problems. If, for example, a bad railway investment is made which fails to generate adequate users, the resources transferred within the system to bail it out preclude their availability to build a railway which is actually required. The problem therefore does appear in the form of systemic financial crisis, not for reasons outlined, but in the form of a decline in the economy’s overall investment efficiency, as resources are sucked into inefficient ventures at the expense of efficient ones.
  The data on this latter process is clear. Every major economy suffered a decline in investment efficiency as a result of the international financial crisis. Taking the five years after the start of the financial crisis, the percentage of GDP that had to be invested in China for its economy to grow by one percent rose from 3.4 percent to 4.9 percent – China’s investment efficiency fell under the impact of the global financial crisis. But in the U.S. the percentage of GDP that had to be invested for the economy to grow by one percent rose from 8.1 percent to 33.1 percent! In other words, China came through the negative consequences of the international financial crisis much more successfully than the U.S.
  Because they ignore elementary accounting rules, those claiming that China will suffer a severe “debt crisis” are writing financial fairy stories – they never actually occur.

其他文献
DEEP in the snowy mountains of the Qinghai-Tibet Plateau, legend recalls, is a blessed valley in the shape of an eight-petal lotus. Spectacular snowcapped mountains, steep gorges and alpine meadows sp
期刊
Legacy of a Ming Prime Minister  Xu Guangqi was a legendary figure. His political career was bumpy, yet eventually culminated in the highest position in the Ming imperial court. Furthermore, this dign
期刊
NEW energy vehicles were once again the highlights of Auto China 2014, held at China International Exhibition Center in Beijing in late April. Over 2,000 enterprises from 14 countries participated, ex
期刊
More Time for Reading  A study by the Chinese Academy of Press and Publication shows that the country’s reading rate began to rise in 2005, after a steady downturn from 1999. Results of the 10th natio
期刊
NATIVE culture is a key component of a people’s identity and the cornerstone of a nation’s civilization. It often supplies spiritual drive for social development, catalyzing revolution and innovation.
期刊
IF one were to look at Liu Ye’s paintings dating from the early 1990s and to study carefully the themes he has developed over time, the impression would be like that of a fairy tale; magical, idealize
期刊
ANYONE traveling between Xigaze City and Gyirong County, or between Xigaze City and Saga County via the corridor in front of Mt. Xixabangma, would en route be unable to miss Baiku Co, a large undistur
期刊
THE International Dialogue on the Chinese Dream concluded in Shanghai on December 8, 2013. Attended by nearly 100 experts and scholars from 24 countries, the two-day event enacted international and cr
期刊
THE time-honored Beijing Tongrentang brand has achieved its longstanding goal to go global. The leading Chinese pharmaceutical company has opened 95 stores in 17 countries and regions out of the mainl
期刊
SO, the big day has arrived, you had the interview, what’s next? Probably your first instinct is either Starbucks, Erdinger or back to the hotel for an inroom burger. But don’t slack off just yet – wh
期刊