Path?dependence?in?the?welfare?states

来源 :西江文艺 | 被引量 : 0次 | 上传用户:chj0821031
下载到本地 , 更方便阅读
声明 : 本文档内容版权归属内容提供方 , 如果您对本文有版权争议 , 可与客服联系进行内容授权或下架
论文部分内容阅读
  Introduction
  In the welfare state theories, the new institutional approach has explained incremental changes as institutions adjust at the margin progressively (Jensen, 2009). In the past several decades, historical institutionalism has generally emerged as a significant approach in political science and a major approach of institutional analysis. There lies an assumption that policymaking systems tend to be conservative and find ways of defending existing patterns of policy, as well as the organizations delivering these policies (Peters et al, 2005). As Pierson (2000) points out there are self-reinforcing processes in institutions and thus it is difficult to change to another trajectory once a pattern has been established. Historical institutionalism considers policy-making and political change as a discrete process, characterized by periods of stability - denominated as path dependence.
  Path dependence has become increasingly widespread in economics and social sciences. To some extent, politics differs from economics. But some features such as increasing return processes could be applied into politics. The general idea of path dependence is that the events occurred in the past have an impact on the later ones. It is indicated that the past shapes the future in varying degrees. There is a common “short hand” (Ebbinghaus, 2005). In other words, history matters. Path dependence includes elements of both stability and change. It is crucial to understand path dependence in a dynamic system.
  This article consists of four sections. After briefly give an example of the Polya Urn, the first section gives a literature review of path dependence, which understands path dependence in general sense and in a more open system. The second part is case study, including health reform in the United States and in Britain. Following the part comes discussion. It gives an analysis and comparison of the cases in the United States and Britain, which represents a strong path dependence and a weak path dependence respectively. The final section is conclusion. Even though the NHS system in Britain has experienced policy changes, it could not be easily concluded that it is not suitable for path dependence. And in the end, this essay also considers the constraints and indications of policy-makers.
  Literature Review
  Imaging there is a large urn including two balls of equal size (one black, one white). First, one ball is removed randomly from the urn and its color observed. Then the ball is put back along with an additional ball of the same color. The process is repeated until the urn fills up. What kind of distribution would be eventually in the urn? Every time one ball is removed and returned, it increases the probability of drawing the same color in the next process. I would say, one color would dominate at last even though it is always a random process. Mathematicians call this a Polya urn model. Polya urn processes exhibit positive feedback and capture essential elements of path dependence (Pierson, 2004).   The new institutionalism is an approach that for the purpose of ‘illuminating how political struggles are mediated by the institutional setting in which they take place’ (Thelen and Steinmo, 1992, p.2). The approach is ‘new’ because it tries to stress agency, structure and the role of institutions. In particular, historical institutionalism look more closely at the origins and development of the welfare states, which interprets the limited options and behaviors in a ‘logic of path-dependence’ (Schmidt, 2006). The historical institutionalists are associated with historical development. As Hall and Taylor (1996, p. 940) puts it, path dependence refers to “the rejection of the traditional postulate that the same operative forces will generate the same results everywhere in favor of the view that the effect of such forces will be mediated by the contextual features of a given situation often inherited from the past”. Thus, historical institutionalists often emphasis the high degree of continuity and unintended consequences that result from historical development. Some historical institutionalists also separate a sequence of events into periods of continuity punctuated by critical moments or junctures that shape the basic contours of life, such as institutional change happens and then creates a “branching point” from which historical development moves away from the old path (Collier and Collier, 1991; Krasner, 1988).
  At the heart of historical institutionalism is an image of social causation that is based upon path dependence. In a general sense, the key mechanisms identified in the path dependence literature include positive feedback (or self-reinforcement) and increasing returns. As David (2000, p. 8) puts it, “the core content of the concept of path dependence as a dynamic property refers to the idea of history as an irreversible branching process”. Also, Hacker (2002, p. 54) argues that “path dependence refers to developmental trajectories that are inherently difficult to reverse.” Path dependence refers to dynamic processes involving positive feedback, which generate a number of possible outcomes (Arthur, 1994; David, 2000). In the face of positive feedback, the chance of further steps along the same path would increase with each move down (Pierson, 2004). Every step in one direction makes it a little more difficult to reverse to another. All of them have claimed that positive feedback is a crucial character of a historical process which generates path dependence.   As Mahoney (2000, p. 507) puts it, “path dependence characterizes specifically those historical sequences in which contingent events set into motion institutional patterns or event chains that have deterministic properties.” The understanding of path dependence can be dated back to Arthur. Arthur (1994, p. 112) has argued that there are four features of a technology and its social context generate increasing returns: large set-up costs, learning effects, coordination effects and adaptive expectations. And North (1990) claims that all the four features that Arthur identified in increasing returns of technology can be applied to institutions. In North’s words, “There are large initial setup costs when the institutions are created…. There are significant learning effects for organizations that arise in consequence of the opportunity set provided by the institutional framework…. There will be coordination effects directly via contracts with other organizations and indirectly by induced investments through the polity in complementary activities…. Adaptive expectations occur because increased prevalence of contracting based on a specific institution will reduce uncertainties about the permanence of that rule” (North, 1990, p. 95). A path with increasing return effects will lead to a deterministic framework (Pierson, 2000). That is to say, contingent beginnings create a path with deterministic effects. Here path dependence implies that equilibrium is stable and highly deterministic, but also temporary. Under some circumstances, a series of critical junctures will come up and result in an unexpected new path (Djelic and Quack, 2007).
  It probably comes as no surprise that path dependence theory has been subject to powerful critiques in politics (see Schwartz, 2002; Peters et al, 2005). The most common and well-documented charge levelled against the theory concerns its weak ability to account for endogenously generated change (Ross, 2007). Ross (2007) argues that it is path dependent theory’s fundamental weakness at explaining change.
  However, the strong version of path dependence also acknowledges the possibility of change. According to Djelic and Quack (2007), “the image or model of change is one of punctuated equilibrium”. And the particular sequence of events could be critical moments or junctures for contingent developments, though sometimes they are rare (Mahoney, 2000). Those events for change are in the logic of each path being entrenchment, stability and reproduction, which are considered as “external shocks” to the system (Djelic and Quack, 2007). Ebbinghaus (2005) puts forward two clearly different explanations of path dependence that could be summarized in two metaphors. The first one is “trodden trail that emerges through the subsequent repeated use by others of a path spontaneously chosen by an individual”. The other interpretation is the “road juncture, the branching point at which a person needs to choose one of the available pathways in order to continue the journey”. Thus, this kind of path dependence involves two different ways to make clear historical events. The “trodden trail” and “road juncture” resemble a consistent diffusion path and a branching pathway respectively. The branching pathway concentrates on the particular historical origins of institutions. Historical institutionalists regard institutions as conscious choices by policy actors at critical junctures. But this does not mean institutionalists are well-planned.   A path-dependent sequence of events and political changes are associated with previous decisions and existing institutions (Wilsford, 1994). Different sources of stability will be sensitive to different pressures for change (Djelic and Quack, 2007). The view of Ebbinghaus (2005) allows for more openness to change. The first way is path stabilization. Due to self-reinforcing process and successful gradual adaptation, it shows a long-term stability, and people often call this ‘lock-in’; The second is path departure. It occurs under optimistic environment, and the self-reinforcing mechanisms provide sufficient resources for gradual adaptation. Earlier decisions narrow the choice set but do not determine the next adaptive step. Path departure locates between path stability and radical system change; The last one is path switch,which takes step to end the self-reinforcement of an exsiting institution and establish another trajectory. Therefore, in this perspective, ‘branching pathways’ can explain the different forms of institution stability and change (Ebbinghaus, 2005).
  Case Study
  Policy continuity and change are displayed by a ‘punctuated equilibrium’, with a long period of relative stability followed by sudden and dramatic change (Jensen, 2009). In the path dependent model, established pattern serves as a device for policy reforms, connecting future policy movement along a certain path (Wildford, 1994). Since equilibrium is stable, conclusive and temporary, there is still a possibility of policy changes. As David (1989, p. 4) puts it, “changes in fundamental scientific or engineering knowledge can occasion radical innovation”. Thus in this section, I will give the case of health reform in the United States and Britain in turn.
  The core of the United State welfare state was established during the New Deal, and since then, its history has been the history of the many political intentions. In November 1992, George Bush was defeated and Bill Clinton was elected as the new president. Clinton would like to force American health policy onto a new path and put forward an activist health policy agenda, while Bush has always considered to continue American health policy as its own trajectory. Therefore, the Clintons put forward two new bases of the health care system radically. First, it would set up geographically-based regional health alliances, which were supported by government tax revenues and the contributions of employers and employees. They act as purchasing agents of health care for their members. And these members are ensured a basic package of health care services. Thus, it was actually an insurance-based system. Secondly, the plan would stimulate the competition of provider networks. In order to get packages of health care services at different prices, it requires the cooperation of physicians, hospitals, laboratories and pharmaceutical suppliers in local networks. Therefore, the competition among networks would notionally result in a better and better package and a lower and lower price while every network would provide the basic and comprehensive services to patients. Here lies the key of "managed competition” (Wilsford, 1994). Also, as Enthoven (1993, p. 24) points out, “Managed competition is defined as a purchasing strategy to obtain maximum value for consumers and employers, using rules for competition derived from microeconomic principles. And it is a blending of the competitive and regulatory strategies that have coexisted uneasily for years in the US health care system”. There are three purposes of Clinton plan. The first is to extend basic comprehensive coverage to all the Americans who have no health insurance at all. The second is to reduce the rate of growth in health care expenditure. And last but not least, it aims to save money in order to pay off the federal budget deficit.   Ikenberry (1994) captures the nature of path dependence in a historical institutional approach including “critical junctures and developmental pathways”. Wilsford (1985, 1994, 1995) tries to interpret policy change with the notion of “conjuncture”, including elements of time, space and a window of opportunity. Thus, the possibility of change requires contingent circumstance. Therefore, as Greener (2002, p. 164) puts it, “policy-makers may have to wait for the alignment of a number of factors to create the opportunity to introduce significant change”. However, the Clinton proposal was defeated at the end of the 1993-94 Congress. Wilsford (1994) also argues that the path-dependent model ‘forecast’ all along the failure of such a non-incremental reform (a new path away from the old trajectory) initiative in the American system. The philosophical foundation of American health care system has regarded health care as a private not a public good traditionally. In effect, in the United States, private insurance plays a role of public programme, and it is hard to remove as the public foundations of mature welfare states (Hacker, 2004).
  Given a strong path dependence in the United States, it is crucial for a conjuncture to overturn the structural impediments to big change. Even under the most favorable conjunctural circumstances, the fragmented institutions in the United States still uphold the status quo, pushing health care policy to the trodden path (Wilsford, 1994). Therefore, once a system becomes widespread and deeply rooted, it is extremely difficult to move away from the historical path to a new trajectory.
  However, the health reform in Britain is not that case. It can not be ignored to understand the economic and political context first in which the National Health Service (NHS) has developed in order to review the evolution of health reform in Britain in the 1980s and the 1990s. The public services and public spending which had featured in the post-war period came to a stop because of the oil crises in the 1970s. The Labor government at that time was pushed to adopt austerity economic policies, which brought conflict with its traditional support foundation in the trade union. It signs the end of the corporatist style of politics that had dominated the British government in the 1960s and 1970s. The Conservative government elected in the 1979 speeded up those changes which challenged the legitimacy of Keynesian and sought a framework including the privatization of state-owned enterprises, reductions in taxation and controls over public expenditure (Ham, 2009). In the 1980s, the government mainly paid attention to how to make the NHS more businesslike and efficient. Also, health policy gives a symbol of new public management (Hood, 1991).   As Webster (1998, p. 143-4) puts it, “The Thatcher reforms represent a long-drawn-out sequence of changes, amounting to a process of continuous revolution, in which the end result was not predictable at the beginning, and indeed the whole process of policy-making was akin to a journey through a minefield, advances being made in an erratic manner, as dictated by the exigencies of political opportunism”. After the adoption of a White Paper - Working for Patients - in 1989, the Britain government put forward an ambitious agenda to reform the NHS. This agenda was passed a resolution in 1990 and was set out to implement on April 1, 1991. At the heart of the NHS reform in 1991 was that purchasers of health care were to be apart from providers of care. This was achieved by the establishment of fund-holding general practitioners (GPs), a system of district health authority (DHA) contracts with hospitals, hospitals set up in autonomous trusts, and consultants working on negotiated contracts with the hospital trusts. These were designed to induce competition among providers for the the business of purchasers in order to greater efficiencies, regarded as ‘more health-care services for money spent’ (Wilsford, 1994). Also, Ham (2009, p. 32) argues that “one of the purposes of separating responsibility for purchasing and provision was to stimulate competition between providers in what was often referred to as an internal market”.
  The Major government was described as more consensual and also focus on consultation and building effective working relationships with outside organizations (Baggott, 1995; Baggort and McGregor-Riley, 1999). On the one hand, some previous political commitments were abandoned or weakened. For example, the terms that let trusts set up the service and payment became nonsense. In fact, medical profession successfully defended the valuable consultation contract. On the other hand, The Major government was not afraid to confront organized interests, although with less overt hostility than its predecessor. Because the Major government lacked the resources of Thatcher — notably a smaller parliamentary majority coupled with an increasingly hostile media and a resurgent Labour opposition — it was forced to compromise on policy issues, in particular at the implementation stage (Baggott, 2007). That is the early institutions of NHS limits the behavior and choice of policy-maker, and they have to rely on the medical profession.
  Yet, there are a number of windows of opportunity for reform, which empowered the Thatcher government to overcome the obstacles and introduce big reforms of the NHS. Also, Wilsford (1994, 1995) points out the conjunctures of a sequence of events that allowed the reforms to happen, including the increased political authority of the Thatcher government after the 1987 general election, the increased heterogeneity of the medical experts, the emergence of the early  reform management, the advice provided by Enthoven for an alternative organizational structure, and its deficiency of threat to the patients and community (see also Greener, 2002; Enthoven, 1985, 1990).   Pierson, P. (2000) Increasing returns, path dependence, and the study of politics, American Political Science Review 92(4), pp. 251–267.?
  Pierson, P. (2004) Politics in Time: History, Institutions and Social Analysis. Oxford: Princeton University Press.
  Pierson, P. and Skocpol, T. (2002) Historical Institutionalism in Contemporary Political Science. In Political Science: The State of Discipline, edited by I. Katznelson and H. Milner. New York: Norton.
  Ross, F. (2007) An Alternative Institutional Theory to Path Dependence: Evaluating the Greener Model, British Politics, 2 (1), pp. 91-99
  Schmidt, D. (2006) Guest Editor's Introduction: Model-Driven Engineering, Computer, vol. 39, no. 2, pp. 25-31.
  Schwartz, H. (2002) ‘Down the wrong path: path dependence, markets, and increasing returns’, Typescript, University of Virginia.?
  Thelen, K. and Steinmo, S. (1992) ‘Historical institutionalism in comparative politics’, in S. Steinmo, K. Thelen and F. Longstreth (eds) Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Perspective, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  Thelen, K. (2004) How institutions evolve: The political economy of skills in Germany, Britain, the United States, and Japan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
  Webster, W. (1998) Imagining Home: Gender, ‘race’, and National Identity, 1945-64, Psychology Press.
  Wilsford, D. (1985) The Conjuncture of Ideas and Interests, Comparative Political Studies,18, pp. 357–372.
  Wilsford, D. (1994) Path-Dependency, or Why History Makes It Difficult, but Not Impossible to Reform Health Care Services in a Big Way, Journal of Public Policy, 14, pp. 251–283.
  Wilsford, D. (1995) States Facing Interests: Struggles over Health Care Policy in Advanced Industrial Democracies, Journal of Health Politics, Policy, and Law, 20, pp. 571–613.
其他文献
【摘要】:医学经验与实验是医学思维的主要来源,而医学的直接经验与实验又在一定的理论指导下进行。在获取经验与实验结果的过程中,无时无刻不伴随着哲学思维的方式和方法,本文拟从哲学思维及其基本方法来探索哲学思维在医学思维中的应用。  【关键词】:医学思维;哲学思维;作用  众所周知,思维方法是认识过程中必不可少的内容和形式。哲学思维方法是人们的认识活动——感性认识上升为理性认识,理性认识回溯到实践这一过
期刊
【摘要】:京津冀一体化、新型城镇化建设以及新农村建设发展战略的提出,标志着农村现代化发展已成为河北省稳定、健康、持续发展的主要动力和支撑。立足河北省传统村镇的特点以及发展现状,通过实地调研,借鉴已有经验和成功实践,对河北省地区传统村镇的现代化发展道路进行了探讨,明确了多元价值开发对传统村镇现代化发展的重要性和必要性,提出了可行的多元价值开发实践途径和指导思想,希望对有关工作有一定借鉴意义和实用价值
期刊
【摘要】:儒释道是中国传统思想文化的三大重要组成部件,佛教自汉代传入中国以后,其与儒道形成的三教关系,构成了汉代以后中国思想学术和文化发展的重要内容,而且在一定程度上决定了整个中华思想文化的特点及其发展的走向。因此,改革开放以来,随着对儒释道三家各自历史与思想的研究全面展开和日益深入,对三教关系的研究的重要性和迫切性越来越呈现出来。  【关键词】:儒释道;特点;关系  一、儒家的特点  儒教最主要
期刊
【摘要】:在国有企业改革过程中党员干部承担着非常重要的职责,“两学一做”学习教育实践的贯彻执行对国有企业党建工作的开展有重要的引导作用。不管是在思想上还是在实践上,“兩学一做”学习教育实践对于国有企业全体党员都具有重要影响。基于此,本文就“两学一做”对开展国有企业党建工作的作用展开了详细的研究。  【关键词】:两学一做;国有企业;党建工作;作用  引言  随着我国企业数量的不断增多与规模的不断增大
期刊
【摘要】:从经济权利、社会权利这二个方面,浅谈入城农民和市民权利均等化。  【关键词】:入城农民,市民,经济权利,社会权利,不平等,均等化  在我们每个人出生之后,父母都会给我们报户口。户口与每一个中国人密切相关。户口现象的背后就是户口制度,又称户籍制度。顾名思义,就是对户口、户籍进行管理的制度,是各级国家管理机构对其辖区范围内的户口进行调查、登记、申报,并且按照一定原则进行立户、分类和编制的户口
期刊
【摘要】:近年来,生鲜电子商务亦变得炙手可热,成为了电商领域的一大热点,被称为电子商务领域新的蓝海。在市场需求和科学技术升级的推动下,生鲜电商发展迅速,但是各种突出难题也随之而来。本文首先从生鲜电商概念入手,进而梳理我国生鲜电商发展历程,最后提出生鲜电商市场发展过程中出现的突出问题。  【关键词】:生鲜电商;发展;问题  1.生鲜电商概念   生鲜电商是指生鲜产品电子商务,是其概念的简称,具体是利
期刊
【摘要】:社会不断进步,企业中具备丰富知识的员工人数降低,而且近几年这种现象频繁发生,尤其是对于IT企业,流失人员的数量是非常多的、频率也是非常快的,已经引起了相关企业中高层领导的重点关注。较高的员工流失率,伴随其产生的成本增加、客户的缺失以及资源重新配置等其它的问题,对企业的健康发展造成了非常大的影响,怎样有效的处理好这个问题成了企业家和管理学专家所关注的焦点。本文首先介绍了国内IT企业员工流失
期刊
【摘要】:项目部管理;HSE;工程质量;管理经验;  前 言  施工建设项目是一个系统工程,要想有效的控制工程运行,保证工程按照合同 要求顺利完成,既要完成对业主在工程质量、工期、HSE等各方面的承诺,又要完成公司制定的项目盈利指标。所以,在工程实施的全过程中,我们认真总结与参建各方共同对项目进行行之有效的管理经验,探讨更加科学有效的措施和方法,以确保项目工程工序能够合理可控。  工程项目管理的定
期刊
【摘要】:法律是一种非常普遍的历史现象,在历史过程中,因此法律产生与发展有其规律性。中国古代刑罚有两个阶段,奴隶制刑罚和封建制刑罚。奴隶制刑罚以墨、劓等为主,而封建制以徒、流、死等为主,这两个过程相互联系,又有进步。中国古代刑罚制度结束于清朝末年,满清贵族进行了的刑罚改革。中国古代刑罚的演变和发展受生产力和政治经济的影响,反过来也影响社会的发展,它有轻刑化的趋势。新中国成立以后,人民当家做主,形成
期刊
【摘要】:人口老龄化问题越来越成为重大的社会问题。随着人们生活质量要求的不断提高,全社会对无障碍室内设计的要求日益迫切。老年人越来越受到人们的关心和社会的重视。本论文认真研究了当前世界人口老龄化的趋势,分析了中国当前老年化趋势和未来可能出现的老年人口快速增长的状况,并对老年人的生理、心理特征进行了深入的研究。  【关键词】:老年人;无障碍设计;应用价值  一.老年人的生理、心理特征研究  1.1老
期刊